By Rosemary
Irving and Rosa Hill, University of Canterbury
Rosie and Rosa are undergraduate students. They won the Motu Environment Economics Essay prize in 2017. You can find out more information about Motu's proposal for the Emissions Trading Scheme (ETS) and our wider ETS work.
Rosie Irving and Rosa Hill |
Economic Rationale: How an
Emissions Trading Scheme Works
Figure 1: Command-and-control (equal misery) approach |
Figure 2: Emissions trading scheme approach |
Achieving
emissions reduction through an ETS is done by transferring one unit of reduction
from the emitter with higher marginal costs of abatement (MAC2) to the emitter
with lower costs of marginal abatement (MAC1) through trade. On an aggregate
level, this is the most efficient way to reduce emissions as it costs the
emitter with the lower abatement cost less to undertake the reduction (Hanley,
Shogren & White 2013). On the other hand, command-and-control approaches
create an efficiency loss, with the reduction of emissions (from E to Eopt)
having a higher cost of abatement. Both ETS and command-and-control policies
set a cap for the optimal aggregate quantity of emissions. However, in ETS, the
market sets the price through trade whereas the price in a command-and-control
approach is reflective of the costs of abating to that level (Schmalensee & Stavins, 2017).
The ETS
model recognises the inherent heterogeneity in emissions abatement costs
amongst firms. Unlike command-and-control approaches, where all firms are
regulated to cut emissions by the same amount, market-based approaches such as
the ETS achieve reductions at a lower cost by equating the abatement costs
across sources (Schmalensee &
Stavins, 2017). Cost savings from using a trading program as opposed to command
and control were estimated to be 20% in the U.S. Phasedown of Leaded Gasoline
and to be at least 15% and possibly as great as 90% in the U.S. Sulfur Dioxide
Allowance Trading Program (Schmalensee &
Stavins, 2017). Newell and Stavins (2003) suggests that the greater the differences
in emissions abatement costs across firms, the greater the cost savings are
likely to be from using a market-based approach.
Another key
feature of an ETS’s success is the incentives it provides firms to not only
reduce their emissions but to go beyond minimum requirements. Being able to
sell surplus emission allowances encourages firms to develop technical
innovations that allow them to produce at lower emission levels. This has the
advantage of allowing firms the flexibility to decide the most cost-effective
way to reduce emissions (Schmalensee &
Stavins, 2017).
Photo by Rosa Hills |
Key
Considerations when Establishing an Emissions Trading Scheme
While ETSs
have proven to be an effective mechanism for reducing greenhouse gases, the
program’s success lies in its details and design (Schmalensee & Stavins, 2017). By analysing past
experiences of ETS programs, some key trends in design can be observed as
critical for successful implementation. The following factors are crucial to
starting an ETS program successfully.
Establishing
rules prior to implementation
Establishing
rules and corresponding penalties prior to the program’s implementation increases
compliance, as it limits uncertainty and price volatility and ultimately allows
firms to plan. The importance of establishing rules prior to implementation is
noted in the example of the NOx Trading in the Eastern United States. The
program faced high levels of uncertainty as a result of trading beginning
before some rules were in place. Consequently, there were high levels of price
volatility during the first year of the program (Schmalensee & Stavins, 2017). Establishing rules
early on can assist in limiting policy uncertainty, which is particularly
important in achieving the goals of an ETS as uncertainty can create
unwillingness to invest in innovation to reduce emissions (Lopez, Sakhel & Busch, 2016).
Free initial
allowances
Free initial
allowances are often critical to gaining political support to kick start the
program in its pioneering stage. However, after the initial stage, independent
phasing into allowance auctions becomes important as it allows the market to
set the price without compromising the environmental performance or raising
costs (Schmalensee &
Stavins, 2017).
Low
transaction costs
Low
transaction costs are a contributing factor to the success of trading in ETS
programs such as the Phasedown of Leaded Gasoline and the Sulfur Dioxide
Allowance Trading Programme. If transaction costs are too high like they were
in the US Environmental Protection Agency's early emissions offset systems due
to requirement of government approval prior to trades, significant trading will
not occur (Schmalensee &
Stavins, 2017).
Banking
Banking
allows firms to collect and save permits for later use or trade. The importance
of banking was highlighted in the case of southern California's Regional Clean Air Incentives Market (RECLAIM) in which banking was not
permitted. Faced with the 2000-2001 Californian electricity crisis, the
industry saw a steep increase in allowance prices, resulting in the temporary
suspension of the program (Schmalensee &
Stavins, 2017). It also became critical to allow banking from one phase to the
next to avoid a price collapse, as seen at the close of the EU ETS’s first
phase (Ellerman, Marcantonini
& Zaklan, 2016).
Price
collars
Price
collars set a maximum and minimum price that permits may sell for. This
decreases the risk of major price fluctuations and stabilises costs.
Highlighted through the US Regional Greenhouse Gas Initiative (RGGI), setting a reserve
price for permits enables a price floor, while releasing permits from a reserve
when prices get exceedingly high allows for a price ceiling (Schmalensee & Stavins, 2017). Price
collars become particularly important when economic conditions change. They
prevent the cap from becoming non-binding if emissions fall below it as well as
prevent excessive price spikes from occurring when the economy experiences
growth (Schmalensee &
Stavins, 2017).
Leakage
Leakage poses
a potential to impair the effectiveness of the ETS. Leakage occurs when
emission production is moved outside of the regulated area into a less
stringent area. Leakage can also occur when firms sell their older, more
polluting equipment and firms in sectors of less stringent regulations purchase
it (Wrake, Burtraw, Lofgren & Zetterberg, 2012). In RGGI, only nine northeastern states currently take part. Because some
states border others which have not been part of the initiative, there has been
significant possibility of leakage (Schmalensee
& Stavins, 2017).
Reference List:
Ellerman,
A. M. (2016). The European Union Emissions Trading System: Ten Years and
Counting. Review of Environmental Economics and Policy, 10(1), 89-107.
Hanley,
N. H. (2013). Introduction to Environmental Economics (Vol. 2nd). USA:
Oxford University Press.
Lopez,
J. M. (2016). Corporate investments and environmental regulation: The role of
regulatory uncertainty, regulation-induced uncertainty, and investment history.
European Management Journal (35), 91-101.
Newell,
R. G. (2003). Cost heterogeneity and the potential savings from market-based
policies. Journal of Regulatory Economics, 23(1), 43-59.
Schmalensee,
R. & R. Stavins (2017). Lessons Learned from Three Decades of Experience with Cap and
Trade. Review of Environmental Economics and Policy, 11(1), 59-79.
Wrake,
M. B. (2012). What Have We Learnt from the European Union's Emissions Trading
System? Royal Swedish Academy of Sciences, 12-22.
No comments:
Post a Comment