Agricultural emissions, caused in part by lots of cows and sheep burping, are responsible for around half of all of New Zealand’s greenhouse gas emissions. New Zealand faces “unusually high costs to cut greenhouse gas emissions” due to the large number of livestock in the country, or so the government is continuing to argue. With Suzi Kerr, I’ve just released a Motu Working Paper looking at methane emissions from NZ agriculture, which comprise 30% of NZ’s agricultural emissions (with 18% being from nitrous oxide), so it seems timely to look at some of the issues regarding methane, and hopefully clear the air on this confusing and complicated topic!
At present, New Zealand is very efficient compared with the rest of the world in producing meat and milk. This fact essentially means that less greenhouse gases are put into the atmosphere to produce a bottle of milk in NZ than anywhere else in the world. Fantastic, right? We can just rest on our laurels and not worry about making are farms more efficient?
According to our
new Working Paper, resting on our laurels is probably not the best idea. As
recent plunges in dairy prices show, NZ’s agriculture sector’s success is
highly vulnerable to the ups and downs of the global market.
As efficient
farmers, it may actually in the best interest of NZ farmers to have
agricultural emissions treated like any other emission in a global agreement on
climate change. To understand the reasoning behind this, it is useful to
consider two worlds (and by world I mean The World, not just NZ!):
- World A: Global agricultural emissions are exempt from climate change policy, but the world still cuts emissions by enough to stay below a 2°C limit to warming.
- World B: Global agricultural emissions are treated the same as all other emissions. A tax (or price) on emissions applies equally to agricultural emissions as it does to emissions from any other source (eg cars, electricity generation and so on). In this world, reductions of non-agricultural emissions do not need to be as high as World A to stay below a 2°C limit to warming, so overall the cost to all the countries of the world of reducing climate change is lower than World A.
In World A, NZ
and our farmers see no advantage relative to other farmers from producing
low-emission milk and meat.
In World B, NZ
farmers are advantaged, relative to other farmers. A global price on
agricultural emissions raises the global price of milk and meat relative to
World A. However, NZ famers also pay the global price for their greenhouse gas
emissions, which could cancel out their gains relative to World A.
The findings
from our paper (and modelling by Andy
Reisinger and Adolf Stroombergen, which we build on) essentially follows
this logic, and gives more details about the magnitudes of costs and benefits
we are talking about. In our modelling NZ farmers have a slight preference for
World A in terms of profitability given that they don’t have to pay for their
emissions, but World B is close behind given the efficiency of our farmers. New
Zealand as a whole is better off in World B relative to World A due to the
lower overall cost of lowering emissions (according to Reisinger and Stroombergen).
Whether or not
the world does much about agricultural emissions, the modelling suggests NZ
farmers could benefit from global action on climate change, particularly around
preventing deforestation and encouraging reforestation. This is because
effective global policy on forestry would likely push up international prices
for meat and milk. The dairy farm we modelled saw an increase in profitability
in both World A and B, relative to a world where there’s no action on climate
change (excluding the costs of damages from climate change); there’s just not
as large an increase in profit in World B compared with A.
While the real
world is of course more complicated than World A and B, the basic message is:
the more NZ can convince other countries to put in place policies to reduce
agricultural emissions, the better it is for the NZ economy and likely too for
NZ farmers over the long term, especially as they become more efficient. There’s
also the usual arguments about protecting our clean and green brand.
How can we do
this? We have discussed elsewhere some of the ways to start reducing agricultural emissions
in NZ – and farmers do currently have options to reduce their emissions,
contrary to popular belief. If NZ starts to enact good policies to reduce
agricultural emissions, we are more likely to be able to convince other
countries to do the same. Good policy may include some transition assistance
for farmers to help with policy implementation in terms of costs and getting
buy-in from farmers, along with addressing any fairness concerns.
If we don’t
follow the path to World B, we will be stuck using our agricultural emissions
as an excuse for inaction and therefore give other countries the excuse to not
reduce their agricultural emissions. In doing this, the cost for NZ is that we
fail to exploit what is actually an advantage to us in a world that is
desperately trying to reduce climate change emissions.
No comments:
Post a Comment